James Meade
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

James Edward Meade, (23 June 1907 – 22 December 1995) was a British
economist An economist is a professional and practitioner in the social sciences, social science discipline of economics. The individual may also study, develop, and apply theories and concepts from economics and write about economic policy. Within this ...
and winner of the 1977
Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences The Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences, officially the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel ( sv, Sveriges riksbanks pris i ekonomisk vetenskap till Alfred Nobels minne), is an economics award administered ...
jointly with the Swedish economist
Bertil Ohlin Bertil Gotthard Ohlin () (23 April 1899 – 3 August 1979) was a Swedish economist and politician. He was a professor of economics at the Stockholm School of Economics from 1929 to 1965. He was also leader of the People's Party, a social-libe ...
for their "pathbreaking contribution to the theory of
international trade International trade is the exchange of capital, goods, and services across international borders or territories because there is a need or want of goods or services. (see: World economy) In most countries, such trade represents a significant ...
and international capital movements". Meade was born in
Swanage Swanage () is a coastal town and civil parish in the south east of Dorset, England. It is at the eastern end of the Isle of Purbeck and one of its two towns, approximately south of Poole and east of Dorchester. In the 2011 census the civil ...
,
Dorset Dorset ( ; archaically: Dorsetshire , ) is a county in South West England on the English Channel coast. The ceremonial county comprises the unitary authority areas of Bournemouth, Christchurch and Poole and Dorset (unitary authority), Dors ...
. He was educated at Malvern College and attended
Oriel College, Oxford Oriel College () is a constituent college of the University of Oxford in Oxford, England. Located in Oriel Square, the college has the distinction of being the oldest royal foundation in Oxford (a title formerly claimed by University College, wh ...
in 1926 to read Greats, but switched to Philosophy, Politics, and Economics and gained an outstanding first. His interest in economics grew from an influential postgraduate year at
Christ's College, Cambridge Christ's College is a constituent college of the University of Cambridge. The college includes the Master, the Fellows of the College, and about 450 undergraduate and 170 graduate students. The college was founded by William Byngham in 1437 as ...
and
Trinity College, Cambridge Trinity College is a constituent college of the University of Cambridge. Founded in 1546 by Henry VIII, King Henry VIII, Trinity is one of the largest Cambridge colleges, with the largest financial endowment of any college at either Cambridge ...
(1930–31), where he held frequent discussions with leading economists of the time including Dennis Robertson and
John Maynard Keynes John Maynard Keynes, 1st Baron Keynes, ( ; 5 June 1883 – 21 April 1946), was an English economist whose ideas fundamentally changed the theory and practice of macroeconomics and the economic policies of governments. Originally trained in ...
. After working in the
League of Nations The League of Nations (french: link=no, Société des Nations ) was the first worldwide intergovernmental organisation whose principal mission was to maintain world peace. It was founded on 10 January 1920 by the Paris Peace Conference that ...
and the
Cabinet Office The Cabinet Office is a department of His Majesty's Government responsible for supporting the prime minister and Cabinet. It is composed of various units that support Cabinet committees and which co-ordinate the delivery of government objecti ...
, he was the leading economist of the early years of
Clement Attlee Clement Richard Attlee, 1st Earl Attlee, (3 January 18838 October 1967) was a British politician who served as Prime Minister of the United Kingdom from 1945 to 1951 and Leader of the Labour Party from 1935 to 1955. He was Deputy Prime Mini ...
's government, before taking professorships at the
London School of Economics , mottoeng = To understand the causes of things , established = , type = Public research university , endowment = £240.8 million (2021) , budget = £391.1 millio ...
(1947–1957) and the
University of Cambridge , mottoeng = Literal: From here, light and sacred draughts. Non literal: From this place, we gain enlightenment and precious knowledge. , established = , other_name = The Chancellor, Masters and Schola ...
(1957–1967).


Early life and education

Meade was born in Dorset, England on June 23, 1907. He was brought up in the city of Bath, Somerset in south-west England. He attended the
Lambrook Lambrook is an independent preparatory school for 615 boys and girls, aged 3–13, set in of Berkshire countryside. History The school was founded in 1860 by Robert Burnside, in a large country house built in 1853 by William Budd. Burnside ini ...
school in Berkshire from 1917 to 1921, where his education revolved around the Greek and Latin languages. In his time in Oriel College, Oxford, Meade switched at the end of his second year from Greats to Philosophy, Politics, and Economics which was a very new concept at that time having started only in 1921. Meade's interest in economics grew due to various reasons. He considered the heavy unemployment in the United Kingdom in the inter-war period as a menace and a social evil. His association with Major C. H. Douglas, to whom he was introduced to by his aunt, helped him come up with a cure for this evil. In 1930 Meade was elected to a fellowship at Hertford College, Oxford. There he received the option of continuing his study of economics as a postgraduate student. In 1930–31 Meade joined Trinity College, Cambridge after being invited to do so by Dennis Robertson whom he met through his great aunt. While in Cambridge Meade became close friends with Richard Kahn, Piero Sraffa,
Joan Robinson Joan Violet Robinson (''née'' Maurice; 31 October 1903 – 5 August 1983) was a British economist well known for her wide-ranging contributions to economic theory. She was a central figure in what became known as post-Keynesian economics. B ...
, and
Austin Robinson Sir Edward Austin Gossage Robinson, (20 November 1897 – 1 June 1993, Cambridge, England) was a University of Cambridge economist. He was an undergraduate at Christ's College, Cambridge, and a fellow of Sidney Sussex College, Cambridge. A clo ...
, forming the Cambridge Circus for economic discussion. Together they started discussing Keynes' work namely the ''
A Treatise on Money ''A Treatise on Money'' is a two-volume book by English economist John Maynard Keynes published in 1930. Summary of the Work In the ''Treatise'' Keynes drew a distinction between savings and investment, arguing that where saving exceeded invest ...
''. Every weekend Keynes appeared and was presented with the circle's discussion over the week by Kahn. They also discussed theories with Keynes when they met on Monday evenings at the political economy club in Keynes' room at King's College.


Career

Meade became a lecturer at Hertford College, Oxford in 1931 and continued until 1937. Meade along with young enthusiasts such as
Roy Harrod Sir Henry Roy Forbes Harrod (13 February 1900 – 8 March 1978) was an English economist. He is best known for writing '' The Life of John Maynard Keynes'' (1951) and for the development of the Harrod–Domar model, which he and Evsey Domar dev ...
,
Henry Phelps Brown Sir Ernest Henry Phelps Brown MBE, FBA (10 February 1906 – 15 December 1994) was a prominent British economist. Early years Phelps Brown was born in Calne, Wiltshire.. He won a scholarship to The Taunton Academy before winning an open schol ...
, Charlie Hitch, Robert Hall,
Lindley Fraser Lindley Macnaghten Fraser (14 August 1904 – 10 March 1963) was a Scottish academic, author, broadcaster and economist. After an academic career, during which he successfully switched from classics to economics, holding university posts in Amer ...
, Maurice Allen, and Eric Hargreaves, who was his old tutor at Oriel College, started the concept of teaching economics as a regular subject for the examination which was relatively new at Oxford. Meade was assigned the responsibility of teaching the whole subject of economic theory. The economics of mass unemployment and international economics interested Meade in particular. At that time Oxford had a really strong branch of the League of Nations Union with Gilbert Murray as its chairman and Margaret Wilson as its secretary. (Wilson married Meade in 1933.) Meade was made a member of the economics section of the League of Nations in Geneva in 1937. He worked as the main editor of the journal "World Economic Survey" and published the 17th and 18th editions. In April 1940 Meade was forced to leave Geneva for England with his family of three children because of the war. He became a member of the Economic Section of the War Cabinet Secretariat in England and remained a member until 1947 rising to the post of Director in 1946. Meade was joined by Lionel Robbins and Keynes and together they used the section to solve everyday economic problems ranging from the rationing system to the pricing policy of nationalized companies. Meade became the professor of trade at
London School of Economics , mottoeng = To understand the causes of things , established = , type = Public research university , endowment = £240.8 million (2021) , budget = £391.1 millio ...
in 1947 where the Economics department was headed by
Lionel Robbins Lionel Charles Robbins, Baron Robbins, (22 November 1898 – 15 May 1984) was a British economist, and prominent member of the economics department at the London School of Economics (LSE). He is known for his leadership at LSE, his proposed def ...
. While he was in Oxford, Meade had written a short textbook titled "An Introduction to Economic Analysis and Policy." Meade believed it was time to rewrite the book while teaching international economics, more precisely the theory of international economic policy. It slowly cultivated into Meade's two books, ''The Balance of Payments'' (1951) and ''Trade and Welfare'' (1955). The first volume ''The Balance of Payments'' stresses the fact that for each of its policy objectives, the government requires a policy tool. The second volume ''Trade and Welfare'' deals with conditions under which free trade makes a country better off and conditions under which it does not. Meade concluded that, contrary to previous beliefs, if a country was already protecting one of its markets from international competition, further protection of another market could be "second best." That is, although the ideal would be to eliminate all trade barriers, if for some reason this was not feasible, then adding a carefully chosen dose of protectionism could improve the nation's economic well-being. The two books took Meade a decade to complete, however, according to him they still did not cover the entire field of international economic policy since he had given less attention to the issue of international aspects of economic growth or dynamic imbalance. Despite his words, Meade shared the Nobel Prize in Economics along with Bertil Ohlin in 1977. In 1957 Meade moved from London to the chair of political economy in Cambridge, which he held until 1967, after which he resigned to become a senior research fellow of
Christ's College, Cambridge Christ's College is a constituent college of the University of Cambridge. The college includes the Master, the Fellows of the College, and about 450 undergraduate and 170 graduate students. The college was founded by William Byngham in 1437 as ...
. Meade left the fellowship at retirement age in 1974. During this time Meade started thinking about writing one or two volumes on the domestic aspects of economic theory and policy. He successfully wrote four volumes in this series namely The Stationary Economy, The Growing Economy, The Controlled Economy, and The Just Economy. Even after the four volumes Meade still believed that he had just made the beginning. He believed that the frontiers of knowledge when it comes to economics keep expanding at such a rate that it was almost impossible to establish a soundly based understanding of the entire subject and its ever-evolving parts. In 1974 Meade took time off to act as full-time chairman of a committee set up by the Institute for Fiscal Studies to examine the structure of direct taxation in the United Kingdom. The committee consisted of a number of first-rate economic theorists and of leading practitioners in tax law, accountancy, and administration. In 1976, he was awarded an Honorary Degree (Doctor of Science) by the
University of Bath (Virgil, Georgics II) , mottoeng = Learn the culture proper to each after its kind , established = 1886 (Merchant Venturers Technical College) 1960 (Bristol College of Science and Technology) 1966 (Bath University of Technology) 1971 (univ ...
. Meade died on 22 December 1995 in Little Shelford, Cambridgeshire.


Meade's model of economic growth

The basic assumptions for J. E. Meade's model are as follows: (1) The economy in question is a closed economy with no relationship with the outside world. (2) There is no government activity involving taxation and expenditure. (3) Perfect competition exists in the market. (4) Constant returns to scale prevail in the economy. (5) There are only two commodities: a consumption good and a capital good. (6) There is full employment of land, labor, and machinery. (7) All machinery are alike and the ratio of labour to machinery can be easily varied, hence there is perfect malleability of machinery. (8) There is perfect substitutability between capital goods, consumer goods, and any given stock of machines, no matter how old or new they are, a certain percentage gets replaced every year. Meade calls this phenomenon the assumption of depreciation by evaporation.


Determinants of the rate of economic growth

According to the assumptions given above, the net output produced by the economy depends on the following four things: (1) The amount of existing stock of machines in the economy (2) The amount of labor for the production process (3) The amount of land or natural resources available for productive use in the economy (4) The technological progress in the economy is expected to improve over time. Hence the production function for the economy is given by: : Y = F (K,L,N,t) Where: Y = net output or net real income K = existing stock of machines L = the amount of labour N = amount of land t = time Time is accounted for because with the passage of time the production would increase without any increase in K , L , or N . An increase in Y with time (denoted by \Delta Y ) can take place in three ways. First, the machine stockpile may increase if the community starts saving part of its income thereby accumulating real capital. If the increase in the stock of capital taking place in one year is given by \Delta Y , the output would increase by V \Delta K where V denotes the marginal net physical product of a machine. Secondly, L , the working population, may grow. If \Delta L denotes an increase in the amount of labour productivity employed in a single year and W measures the marginal product of labour, the output will increase in that year by W \Delta L . Finally, the net output can increase if there is an increase in technical progress (hence enabling increased efficiency). The total increase in net output due to technical progress is given by \Delta Y' . Hence the total increase in net output in one year is the sum of the three influences. Combining this we get the equation: \Delta Y = V \Delta K + W \Delta L + \Delta Y' Dividing both sides by Y , we get \frac = \frac . \Delta K + \frac \Delta L + \frac Or, \frac = \frac . \frac + \frac . \frac + \frac (Equation 1) Here \frac is the annual proportionate rate of growth of output, \frac the annual proportionate rate of growth of machinery stock, \frac the annual proportionate rate of growth of productively employed labour and \frac the annual proportionate rate of growth of output due solely to increase in technical progress. Meade denotes these four proportionate rates of growth as y , k , l and r respectively. \frac is the proportion of net national income to be paid in net profits (provided the owners of machinery receive a reward equal to the value of the net marginal product of the machinery). Meade denotes this as U and calls it "the proportional marginal product of machinery". Under the assumption of constant returns to scale, it is equal to the proportion of national income received in profits. Similarly, \frac represents the proportional marginal product of labour and is equal to the proportion of the net national income going to wages under conditions of constant-returns competitive equilibrium. Meade denotes this as Q . Hence equation 1 can be written as Y = UK +Ql + r (Equation 2) This shows the growth rate of output y as being the weighted sum of three other growth rates, the sum of the growth rate in the stock of machines k weighted by the marginal importance of machinery in the production process i.e., in a competitive equilibrium by the proportion of the national income going to profits U plus the growth rate of the population I weighted by the marginal importance of labour in the production process or, in a competitive equilibrium by the proportion of income going to wages Q plus the growth rate of technical progress r Hence equation 2 can be written as y - l = Uk - (1 - Q)L + r (Equation 3) Since y - l is the difference between the growth rate of total output and the growth rate of the workforce, the growth rate of the real income per head can be measured. For example, if the total real income is increasing by 10 percent every annum but the working population is growing at 8 percent per annum, the income per head is rising by approximately 2 percent per annum. Equation 3 shows that the growth rate of real income per head (y – l) is the output of three factors. Firstly it is raised by the growth rate in real capital k weighted by its proportional marginal product or by the proportion of net national income which would be paid min profits in a competitive equilibrium U . Secondly, it is depressed by the growth rate in the working population l weighted by one minus the proportional marginal product of labour l - Q . Lastly, it is raised by the amount of technology in the economy r . The element UK in equation 3 can also be written down as \frac. k since the growth rate of machine stock is \frac where S is the proportion of the net national income that is saved. Therefore, we have Uk = US . \frac = SV which expresses the same thing in three forms namely the contribution that capital accumulation makes to the growth rate of the final output. Hence the basic relationship between the growth rate of real income per head and its three basic determinants can be expressed as: y - l = Uk - (1 - Q)l + r y - l = US . \frac - (1 - Q)l + r y - l = SV - (1 - Q)l + r Meade explains the application of these equations by taking a simple numerical example. Suppose the people save one-tenth of their income such that S = and that the marginal product of real capital goods or the market profit rate is 5 percent per annum. Hence V = 5 percent per annum. The contribution of capital accumulation to the growth of output, SV would be one-tenth of 5 percent per annum. Hence ½ percent per annum. The explanation of this is, out of a year's income of 1000, if people save 100 units of product and if a once-for-all addition of 100 units to the stock of machines increases annual output in every future year by 5 units, then the initial annual income of 1000 will be raised by this year's capital accumulation to 1005 or by ½ percent during the course of the year. Assuming initial annual income to be 1000 and the initial machinery stock to be 2000 Y = 1000 and K = 2000 . Similarly, the same thing can be expressed by saying that the stock of machines had increased from 2000 to 2100 or by 5 percent per annum. Then U = \frac = \frac = \frac and Uk = \frac \times 5 = \frac per annum. Thus the contribution of capital accumulation to the growth rate of the final output was one-tenth of 5 percent per year or ½ percent per annum. The same result can be obtained by multiplying the proportion of the national income going to profits U , the proportion of the national income which is saved S , and the annual income to capital stock ratio \frac Our numerical example is: US . \frac = \frac \times \frac \times \frac = \frac percent per annum.


Critical appraisal of Meade's growth theory

The growth theory provided by Meade is neo-Classical in nature. It is simple and attractive as it promises a state of steady economic growth. However, it suffers from a few drawbacks: First, for a steady state of economic growth to exist, technological progress should be assumed to be entirely labour-augmenting. This is a special case of Harrod-neutral technological progress. However, this does not seem to exist in the model. Second, the neoclassical adjustment mechanism depends on the flexibility of factor prices. But if they are not flexible a lot of difficulties are established. For example, in the Keynesian liquidity trap, the interest rate may fail to go down beyond a minimum level hence preventing the capital-output ratio to be high enough to reach growth equilibrium. Third, there is no mention of an investment function in the model. It is assumed to be solely determined by savings. Hence entrepreneurial expectations about the future are not taken into account. Fourth, in the neoclassical models capital is assumed to be jelly-like, homogeneous, and malleable. This assumption is truly unrealistic, but without it present, it becomes very difficult to reach a stage of steady growth. Finally, technological progress is considered to be totally exogenous which is again extremely unrealistic and has been pointed out by many economists. To sum up, the neoclassical growth model of Meade is based on certain restrictive and unrealistic assumptions. Hence applying this model in the case of underdeveloped nations is almost impossible since the assumptions of perfect competition, full employment of labour and machinery, and constant returns to scale do not fit in their economic realities.


Other contributions

Professor Meade made other contributions to economics. For example, he showed that the labour-managed firm (or
worker cooperatives A worker cooperative is a cooperative owned and self-managed by its workers. This control may mean a firm where every worker-owner participates in decision-making in a democratic fashion, or it may refer to one in which management is elected by ...
) need not respond inefficiently to price rises even in theory. Along with fellow
Neo-Keynesian The neoclassical synthesis (NCS), neoclassical–Keynesian synthesis, or just neo-Keynesianism was a neoclassical economics academic movement and paradigm in economics that worked towards reconciling the macroeconomic thought of John Maynard Key ...
economist
James Tobin James Tobin (March 5, 1918 – March 11, 2002) was an American economist who served on the Council of Economic Advisers and consulted with the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, and taught at Harvard and Yale Universities. He devel ...
in 1980, Meade proposed nominal GDP targeting as a monetary policy rule during his Nobel Prize memorial lecture on 8 December 1977.


Published works

His books include: * ''The Theory of International Economic PolicyThe Balance of Payments'' (1951) * ''The Theory of International Economic PolicyTrade and Welfare'' (1955) * ''Principles of Political Economy'' (1965–76) * ''The Intelligent Radical's Guide To Economic Policy'' (1975) * ''Liberty, Equality and Efficiency'' (1993)


Notes


References

* *


External links

*
Short autobiography by James Meade

Catalogue of the Meade papers
at th

of the
London School of Economics , mottoeng = To understand the causes of things , established = , type = Public research university , endowment = £240.8 million (2021) , budget = £391.1 millio ...
. *
Time.dufe.edu.cn
* including the Prize Lecture 8 December 1977 ''The Meaning of "Internal Balance"'' {{DEFAULTSORT:Meade, James 1907 births 1995 deaths Nobel laureates in Economics British Nobel laureates Alumni of Trinity College, Cambridge Alumni of Oriel College, Oxford Academics of the London School of Economics People from Swanage People educated at Malvern College Companions of the Order of the Bath Fellows of the British Academy Foreign associates of the National Academy of Sciences English Nobel laureates Fellows of Hertford College, Oxford Fellows of Christ's College, Cambridge 20th-century British economists Social Democratic Party (UK) politicians Universal basic income in the United Kingdom Professors of Political Economy (Cambridge, 1863)